George Friedman
Eurozone countries on June 9
agreed to lend Spain up to 100 billion euros ($125 billion) to stabilize the
Spanish banking system. Because the bailout dealt with Spain's financial sector
directly rather than involving the country's sovereign debt, Madrid did not
face the kind of demands for more onerous austerity measures in exchange for
the loan that have led to political instability in countries such as Greece.
There are two important
aspects to this. First, yet another European financial problem has emerged
requiring concerted action. Second, unlike previous incidents, this bailout was
not accompanied by much melodrama, infighting or politically destabilizing threats.
The Europeans have not solved the underlying problems that have led to these
periodic crises, but they have now calibrated their management of the situation
to minimize drama and thereby limit political fallout. The Spanish request for
help without conditions, and the willingness of the Europeans to provide it,
moves the European process to a new level. In a sense, it is a capitulation to
the crisis.
This is a shift in the
position of Europe's creditor nations, particularly Germany. Berlin has realized
that it has no choice but to fund this and other bailouts. As an
export-dependent country, Germany needs the eurozone to be able to buy German
products. Moreover, Berlin cannot allow internal political pressures to
destabilize the European Union as a whole. For all the German bravado about
expelling countries, the preservation and even expansion of the existing system
remains a fundamental German interest. The cycle of threats, capitulation by
creditors, political unrest and then German accommodation had to be broken. It
was not only failing to solve the crisis but also contributing to the
eurozone's instability. In Spain, the Germans shifted their approach, resolving
the temporary problem without a fight over more austerity.
The problem with the solution
is that it does nothing to deal with the larger dilemma of European sovereignty
and debt. Germany is taking responsibility for solving Spain's banking problem
without having any control over the Spanish banking system. If this becomes the
norm in Europe, then Germany has moved from the untenable threat of expelling
countries to the untenable promise of underwriting them. Europe, in other
words, has accommodated itself to the perpetual crises without solving them.
In our view, the root of the
problem is the struggle to align the world's second-largest exporter with a
bloc of nations that ought to be enjoying positive trade balances but are
instead experiencing trade deficits. Germany, however, views the root of the
problem as undisciplined entitlement and social program spending that leads to
irresponsible borrowing practices. Thus the Europhiles, led by Germany, don't
look for solutions by redefining the European trading system, but rather by
disciplining countries, particularly within the eurozone, on their spending and
borrowing practices.
According to a report in
German magazine Der Spiegel, European Central Bank President Mario Draghi,
Eurogroup President Jean-Claude Juncker, European Council President Herman Van
Rompuy and European Commission President Jose Manuel Barroso are drafting a
plan to stabilize the system. Under the purported plan, all eurozone members
would be required to balance their budgets. Borrowing would be permitted only
if approved by a Europe-wide finance minister, a position that would have to be
created and supported by a select group of eurozone finance ministers. If
approved, money could be borrowed by issuing eurobonds.
The report appears to be well
grounded, with European leaders confirming that the four individuals are working
on a plan (though they did not confirm the plan's details). The approach
outlined in the report would attempt to resolve Europe's problems by increasing
the Continent's political integration -- a concept that has been discussed
extensively, particularly by the Germans and Europhiles. Given the
circumstances, this would seem to be a reasonable position. If all of Europe is
going to be responsible for sovereign debt issued by member countries, then the
stakeholders who have the most invested in the European project must have
control over borrowing. The moral hazard of de facto guarantees on borrowing
without such controls is enormous.
There are two problems
inherent in this approach. The first, as we have said, is the assumption that
Europe's core problem is irresponsible borrowing and that if borrowing were
controlled, the European problem would be solved. Irresponsible borrowing is
certainly part of the problem, but the deeper issue is trade.
The European Union is built
around Germany and therefore the sort of economic dynamism that Germany enjoyed
in the 1950s and 1960s, when the country benefited from access to the U.S.
market while retaining some protection for its own emerging industries.
Eurozone countries' inability to cover debt payments stems in part from their
inability to compete with Germany. Under normal circumstances, the economies of
developing countries grow through exports driven by lower wage rates, but the
shared currency prevents developing European countries from taking advantage of
low wages. Borrowing may be too high, but Germany's dependence on exports makes
it impossible for Berlin to allow a Greece or a Spain the time and space to
develop critical economic sectors in the way that the United States allowed
Germany to develop after World War II.
The second problem is the more
serious one. The ability to manage a national budget, including the right to
borrow, is a central element of national sovereignty. If the right to borrow is
transferred from national governments to unelected functionaries appointed by a
multinational entity, a profound transformation of democracy in Europe will
take place. The European Union has seen transfers of sovereign rights from
national governments and their electorates before, but none as profound as this
one. Elected governments will not be able to stimulate their economies without
approval of this as-yet-unnamed board, nor will they be able to undertake
long-term capital expenditures based on the issuance of bonds. This board thus
will have enormous power within individual countries.
This prospective solution
involves more than simply an attempt to solve banking and debt problems. It
reflects a fundamental principle of European political philosophy: the belief
that disinterested officials are likely to render better decisions than
interested politicians. This idea derives from deep in European intellectual
history. Georg Hegel, a German philosopher, made the argument that the end of
history was its full rationalization, represented by the rational and disinterested
civil servant. Jean-Jacques Rousseau distinguished between the general will and
the popular will. He argued that the latter did not represent the interests of
the people but that the general will, the source of which was not altogether
clear, did.
There is a strand of thought
in Europe that regards the disinterested professional as both safer and likely
to make better decisions than the popular will and its politicians. This is not
an altogether anti-democratic view, but it is a view that says that politics
must be moderated by disinterested experts. This idea heavily influenced the
structure that was created to manage the European Union and is clearly behind
the idea of a European budget board.
The question of the budget is
central to a democracy and a highly politicized process. It is one of the
places in which the public and its representatives can debate the direction in
which the nation should go. The argument has been made that the public and its
politicians cannot be trusted with absolute power in this area and that power
should be limited to unelected people. In a sense, it is the same argument that
has been made for central banks, with even greater power.
The problem, of course, is
that the decisions made by this board will be highly political. First, the
board must be appointed. The selection of the chief eurozone finance minister
and the finance ministers represented on the board will be determined in some
process that likely will not take the views of average European citizens into
account. Second, the board will make decisions that will determine how the
citizens of individual nations live. The board derives from a political process
and shapes national life. It is apolitical only in the sense that its members
don't stand for election by the populations they oversee and thus are not
answerable to them.
There was a similar agreement
before the current crisis called the Stability and Growth Pact, which said that
the national deficit of a European nation could not exceed a certain percentage.
If the deficit did, the nation would pay massive fines. The French (and even
the Germans) consistently exceeded these limits but did not pay fines. They
were too powerful to be sanctioned, so the system broke down.
Today, we see a concept that
goes far beyond the Stability and Growth Pact. The idea is that nations will
have no deficits without the permission of an appointed board and that any debt
they do take on will be issued through an EU mechanism. That mechanism will
eliminate the option of cheating. It may be possible to issue unauthorized
bonds, but without a European guarantee, the market would charge a country like
Greece prohibitively high interest rates.
But the core problem is the
decision about who will and will not be allowed to borrow. Ideally, this
decision would be completely transparent and predictable. In practice, the
differences and needs of different countries will be so vast that the board
will have to make some decisions. Given that the board will be composed of the
finance ministers of some eurozone countries -- and that they will have to go
home after a decision -- the question of who will be denied permission will be
perceived as highly political and, in some cases, as extremely unfair. In some
cases, both will be true.
The ultimate issue has nothing
to do with economics, save for the trade issue. It is a question of the extent
to which European publics are prepared to cede significant elements of national
sovereignty in exchange for secured lines of credit, subject to the authority
of people they never elected. For EU supporters, the notion that political
leaders must be selected by the people they govern is not an absolute. Rational
governance by disinterested leaders is an alternative and, at times, a
preferred alternative. This is not entirely alien to the European tradition. In
practice, however, it could create an explosive situation. The board will
determine its willingness to grant deficits based on its own values. It may not
permit deficits to fund hospitals for the poor. It may allow borrowing to fund
bank bailouts. Or the reverse.
In any event, by taking power
from the electorate, it risks a crisis of legitimacy.
The system has evolved to a
point where, to some Europeans, this crisis of legitimacy may be preferable to
the current cycle of endless crises. It may work for a time. But the first time
a nation's government is thwarted from borrowing to fund a project while
another nation is allowed to borrow for its project, a new crisis will emerge.
Who in the end will determine which deficit is permitted and which is denied?
It will not always be the representatives of the country denied. And that will
create a crisis.
During the U.S. Civil War, the
future of the Union was challenged by the secession of the South. The decisions
were made on the battlefields where men were willing to die either for the
Union or to break away from it. Who will die for the European Union? And what
will hold it together when its decisions are unpopular? The concept of extended
integration can work, but not without the passion that moves a Greek or a
German to protect his and his country's interest. Without that, the glue that
holds nations together is missing in the European Union. The greater the
integration, the more this will reveal itself.
George Friedman, Stratfor,
June 12, 2012
Nenhum comentário:
Postar um comentário
Não publicamos comentários de anônimos/desconhecidos.
Por favor, se optar por "Anônimo", escreva o seu nome no final do comentário.
Não use CAIXA ALTA, (Não grite!), isto é, não escreva tudo em maiúsculas, escreva normalmente. Obrigado pela sua participação!
Volte sempre!
Abraços./-