George Friedman
An important disconnect over
the discussion of the
future of the European Union exists, one that divides into three parts. First, there is the
question of whether the various plans put forward in Europe plausibly could
result in success given the premises they are based on. Second, there is the
question of whether the premises are realistic. And third, assuming they are
realistic and the plans are in fact implemented, there is the question of
whether they can save the European Union as it currently exists.
The plans all are financial
solutions to a particular set of financial problems. But regardless of whether
they are realistic in addressing the financial problem, the question of whether
the financial issue really addresses the fundamental
dilemma of Europe — which is political and geopolitical — remains.
STRATFOR has examined the
plans for dealing with the financial crisis in Europe, and we find them
technically plausible, even if they involve navigating something of a
minefield. The eurozone’s bailout fund, the European Financial Stability
Facility, would be expanded in scope and reach until it can handle the bailout
of a major state, the default of a minor state and a banking crisis of
unprecedented proportions. Given assumptions of the magnitude
of the problem and assuming general compliance with the plans, there
is a chance that the solution we see the Germans moving toward could work.
The extraordinary complexity
of the plans being floated in Europe is important to note. It is extremely
difficult for us to understand the specifics, and we suspect the politicians
proposing it are also less than clear on them. We have found that the more
uncertain the solution, the more complex it is. And the complexity of the
European situation is less driven by the complexity of the economics than by
the complexity of the politics. The problem is relatively easy: Banks and
countries under massive financial pressure almost certainly will default
without extensive aid. By giving them money, default can be avoided. But the
political complexity of giving them money and the opposition
by many Europeans on all sides to this solution contributes to the
complexity. The greater the complexity, the more interests can be satisfied and
— ultimately — the less understanding there is about what has been promised.
Some subjects require complexity, and this is one of them. The degree of
complexity in this case tells another tale.
The Foundation of the
Crisis
Part of that tale is about two
dubious assumptions at the foundation of the crisis. The first is the
assumption that interested parties are genuinely aware of the size of the
financial problems, and to the extent they are aware of it, that they are being
honest about it. Ever since 2008, the singular truth of the financial community
globally has been that they were either unaware of the extent of the financial
problems on the whole or unaware of the realities of their own institutions. An
alternative explanation is, of course, willful ignorance. This translates as
the leaders being fully aware of the magnitude of the problem but understating
it to buy time or to position themselves personally for better outcomes. It
could also simply be a case of their being engaged in helpless hopefulness —
that is, they knew there was nothing they could do but remained hopeful that
someone else would find a solution. In sum, it combined incompetence, willful
deception and willful delusion.
Consider the charge that the
Greeks falsified
financial data. While undoubtedly true, it misses the point. The job of
bankers is to analyze data from loan applicants and to uncover falsehoods. The
charge against the Greeks can thus be extended to bankers. How could they not
have discovered the Greek deception?
There are two answers. The
first is that they didn’t want to. The global system of compensation among
financial institutions — from home mortgages to the purchase of government
bonds — separates the transaction from the outcome. In other words, in many
cases bankers are not held responsible for the outcome of the loan and are paid
for the acquisition and resale of the loan alone. They are therefore not
particularly aggressive in assessing the quality of a given loan. Frequently,
they work with borrowers to make their debt look more attractive.
During the U.S. subprime
crisis, in the mortgage
crisis in Central Europe and in the sovereign debt and banking crisis
in Europe, the system placed a premium on transactions, immunizing bankers from
the repayment of loans. The validity of the numbers systematically were skewed
toward the most favorable case.
More important, such numbers —
not only of the status of loans but also about the economic and social status
of the debtors — inherently are uncertain. This is crucial because part of the
proposed European solution is the imposition of austerity on debtor nation
states. The specifics of that austerity and its effect on the ability to repay after
austerity heavily depend on the validity of available economic and social
statistics.
There is an interesting
belief, at least in the advanced industrial countries, that government-issued
statistics reflect reality. The idea is that the people who issued these
statistics are civil servants, impervious to political pressure and therefore
likely providing accurate data. A host of reasons exists for looking at
national statistics with a jaundiced eye beyond the risk of politicians
pressuring civil servants.
For one, collecting statistics
on a society is a daunting task. Even small countries have millions of people.
The national statistical database is based on the assumption that all of the
transactions and productions of these millions can be measured accurately, or
at least measured within some knowable range of error. This is an overwhelming
undertaking.
The solution is not the actual
counting of transactions — an impossible task — but the creation of statistical
models that make assumptions based on various methodologies. There are
competing models that provide different outcomes based on sampling procedures
or mathematical models. Even without pressure from politicians, civil servants
and their academic mentors have personal commitments to certain models.
The center of gravity of our
global statistical system, particularly those of advanced industrial countries,
is that the selection of statistical models is frequently subject to complex
disputes of experts who vehemently disagree with one another. This is also a
point where political pressure can be applied. Given the disagreements, the
decision on which methodology to use — from sampling to reporting — is subject
to political decisions because the experts are divided and as contentious as
all human beings are on any subject they care about.
And this is the point at which
outside decisions are made, based on outcome, not on the subtleties of
mathematical modeling. There is a connection between the numbers and reality,
but the mathematics of a bailout rests on a statistical base of sand. It is
always assumed that this is the case in the developing world. This creates a
certain advantage, in that it is understood that the statistics are unreliable.
By contrast, the advanced industrial countries have the hubris to believe that
complex mathematics has solved the problem of knowing what hundreds of millions
of people in billions of transactions actually have done.
A Culture of Opaque States
Compounding this challenge,
the European Union has incorporated societies on its periphery that never have
accepted the principle that states must be transparent, a problem exacerbated
by EU regulations. Southern and Central Europeans always have been less
impressed by the state than Germans, for example. This is not simply about
paying taxes but about a broader distrust of government, something deeply
embedded in history. Meanwhile, regulations from Brussels, whose tax and
employment laws make entrepreneurship and small business ownership
extraordinarily difficult, have forced a good deal of the economy “off the
books,” aka, underground.
While not an EU state, Moldova
— said to be the poorest country in Europe — is an instructive example. When
I visited it a year ago, the city (and villages outside the city) were
filled with banks (from Societe Generale on down) and BMWs. There was clear
poverty, but there also was a wealth and vibrancy not captured in
intergovernmental statistics. The numbers spoke of grinding poverty; the
streets spoke of a more complex reality.
What exactly is the state of
the Greek, Spanish or Italian economy? That is hard to say. Official statistics
that count the legal economy suffer from methodological uncertainty. Moreover,
a good deal of the economy is not included in the numbers. One assessment says
that 10 percent of all employees are off the books. Another says 40 percent of
Greeks define themselves as self-employed. A third estimates that 40 percent of
the total Greek economy is in the grey sector. When evaluating what tries to
remain hidden, you’re reduced to guesswork. No one really knows, any more than
anyone really knows how many illegal immigrants are participating in the U.S.
economy. The difference, however, is that this knowledge is of profound
importance to the entire EU bailout.
The level of indebtedness and
the ownership of the debt of European banks and countries are as murky as who
held asset-backed securities in the United States. Yet there is a precise plan
designed to solve a problem that can’t be quantified or allocated. The
complexity and precision of the plan fails to recognize the uncertainty because
the governments and banks are loath to admit that they just aren’t certain. The
banks have grown so big and their relationships so complex that the uncertainty
principle parallels the state’s. The United States — where the same governing
authority handles all fiscal, monetary and social policies — powered through
such uncertainties in the 2008 financial crisis by sheer mass and speed.
Europe, with dozens of (often competing) authorities, so far has found it
impossible to exercise that option.
The countries that face
default and austerity have no better understanding of their own internal
reality than the financial institutions understand their own internal reality.
Greek numbers on the consequences of austerity for government workers do not
take into account that many of those workers show up to work only occasionally
while working another job that is not taxed or known to the state statistical
services. Thus, one has a complete split between the state and banking systems’
ability to honor debt obligations, the insistence
on austerity and the social reality of the country.
Germany has always been
different. Ever since the early 19th century German philosopher Georg Hegel
declared the German civil service had ended history, the idea of the state as
the embodiment of reason has meant something to Germans that it did not mean to
others — in both a noble and a horrible sense. We are now at the noble end of
the spectrum, but the idea that the state is the embodiment of reason still
doesn’t capture the European reality. The Brussels bureaucracy is based on the
German view that a disinterested civil servant can produce rational solutions
that partisan politicians and self-interested citizens could not.
The founding concept of the
European Union involves joining nations that do not share this view, and even
find it bizarre, with a nation for which it is the cultural core. This has
created the fundamental existential issue in the European Union.
The realization that the
rational civil servants of Brussels and Berlin have failed to create systems
that understand reality strikes at German self-perceptions. There is a willful
urge to retain the perception that they understand what is going on. From the
standpoint of Southern and Central Europe, the realization that the Germans
genuinely thought that the states on the EU periphery had reached the level of
precision of the German civil services (assuming Germany had in fact reached
that stage), or that they even wanted to, is a shock. Their publics, which saw
the European Union as a means of getting in on German prosperity without
undergoing a massive social upheaval putting the state and the civil service —
disciplined and rational — at the center of their society, experienced an even
greater shock.
The political and geopolitical
problem is simply this: Germany is unique in Europe in terms of both size and
values. It tried to create a free trade zone based on German values allied with
France that looked at the world in a much more complex way. The crisis we are
seeing, which Germany is trying to solve with extraordinary complexity and
precision, rests on a highly unstable base. First, the European banking system,
like the American banking system, does not understand its status. Second, the
entire mathematics of national statistics is inherently imprecise. Third, the
peripheral countries of the European Union have economies that cannot be
measured at all because their informal economies are massive. The fundamental
principles and self-conception of Germany and Central Europe diverge massively.
The elites of these countries might like to think of themselves as Europeans
first — by the German definition — but the publics know they are not, and they
don’t want to be.
The precision of the bailout
schemes reveals the
underlyingmisunderstanding of reality by Europe’s elites, and specifically by the
Germans. To be more precise, this is willful misunderstanding. They all know
that their precision rests on a foundation of uncertainty. They are buying time
hoping that prosperity will return, mooting all of these problems. But the
problem is that a precise solution to a vastly uncertain problem is unlikely to
return Europe to its happy past. Reality — or rather the fundamental unreality
of Europe — has returned.
In some sense, this is no
different from the United States and China. But the United States has its
Constitution and the Civil War’s consequences to hold itself together in the
face of this problem, and China
has the Communist Party’s security apparatus to give it a shot.
Europe, by contrast, has nothing to hold it together but the promise of
prosperity and the myth of the rational civil servant — the cultural and
political side of the underlying geopolitical problem.
George Friedman, Stratfor –Geopolitical weekly, october 4, 2011, republished with permission of STRATFOR.
Related:
Nenhum comentário:
Postar um comentário
Não publicamos comentários de anônimos/desconhecidos.
Por favor, se optar por "Anônimo", escreva o seu nome no final do comentário.
Não use CAIXA ALTA, (Não grite!), isto é, não escreva tudo em maiúsculas, escreva normalmente. Obrigado pela sua participação!
Volte sempre!
Abraços./-